Arguments against immigration come across our guest poster’s desk every day but their variety is limited. “Rarely,” says Alex Nowrasteh, “do I encounter a unique one. Several times a year I give presentations about these arguments and rebut their points. These are the main arguments against immigration and my quick responses to them.”
1. “Immigrants will take our jobs and lower our wages, especially hurting the poor.”
This is the most common argument and also the one with the greatest amount of evidence rebutting it. First, the displacement effect is small if it even affects natives at all. Second, the debate over immigrant impacts on wages is confined to the lower single digits – immigrants may increase the relative wages for some locals by a tiny amount and decrease them by a larger amount for the few locals who directly compete against them. Immigrants likely compete most directly against other immigrants so the effects on less-skilled native-born folk might be very small or even positive. Third, by increasing the labour pool, immigrants in general allow more total productivity in a place:more productivity, more goods; more goods, more real wealth, not less.
New American research by Harvard professor George Borjas on the effect of the Mariel Boatlift – a giant shock to Miami’s labour market that increased the size of its population by 7 percent in 42 days – does find large negative wage effects concentrated on Americans with less than a high school qualification. To put the scale of that shock to Miami in context however, it would be as if 300,000 immigrants moved to New Zealand in a six-week period – which will not happen. Some doubt Borjas’ finding (here is Borjas’ response to the critics and here is a summary of the debate) but what is not in doubt is that immigration has increased the wages and income of Americans on net. The smallest estimates of immigration surplus, as it is called, is equal to about 0.24 percent of GDP – which excludes the gains to immigrants and just focuses on those to locals.
2. “Immigrants abuse the welfare state.”
Most legal immigrants to the US do not have access to means-tested welfare for their first five years, and New Zealanders lack access to Australian welfare at all, unless naturalised. So allowing access to welfare would be a policy choice.
In any case, immigrants to the US at least are less likely to use means-tested welfare benefits that similar native-born Americans. When they do use welfare, the dollar value of benefits consumed is smaller. If poor native-born Americans used Medicaid at the same rate and consumed the same value of benefits as poor immigrants, the program would be 42 percent smaller.
Immigrants to the US also make large net contributions to Medicare and Social Security, the largest portions of the welfare state, because of their ages, ineligibility, and their greater likelihood of retiring in other countries. Far from draining the welfare state, immigrants have given the entitlement portions a few more years of operation before bankruptcy. If you’re still worried about immigrant use of the welfare state, as I am, then it is far easier and cheaper to build a higher wall around the welfare state, instead of around the country.
3. “Immigrants are a net fiscal cost.”
Related to the welfare argument is that immigrants consume more in government benefits than they generate in tax revenue. The American empirics on this are fairly consistent – immigrants in have a net-zero impact on government budgets (the published version of that working paper is published here).
It seems odd that poor immigrants don’t create a larger deficit but there are many factors pushing explaining that. The first is that higher immigrant fertility and the long run productivity of their children generates a lot of tax revenue. The second is that immigrants grow the economy considerably (this is different from the immigration surplus discussed above) and increase tax revenue. The third is that many immigrants generally come when they are young but not young enough to consume public schools, thus they work and pay taxes before consuming hundreds of thousands of dollars in public schools costs and welfare benefits – meaning they give an immediate fiscal boost. There are many other reasons as well.
Although the tax incidence from immigrants is what matters for the fiscal consequences, between 50 percent and 75 percent of illegal immigrants comply with federal tax law. US states that rely on consumption or property taxes tend to garner a surplus from taxes paid by unlawful immigrants while those that rely on income taxes do not.
4. “Immigrants increase economic inequality.”
In a post-Piketty world, the argument that immigration is increasing economic inequality within nations is getting some attention. While most forms of economic inequality are increasing among people within nations, global inequality is likely falling due, and is at a historic low point due to rapid economic growth in much of the world over the last generation.
The evidence on how immigration affects economic inequality is mixed – some research finds relatively small effects and others find substantial ones. The variance in findings can be explained by research methods – there is a big difference in outcomes between a study that measures how immigration affects economic inequality only among natives and another study that includes immigrants and their earnings. Both methods seem reasonable but the effects on inequality are small compared to other factors.
Frankly, I don’t see the problem if an immigrant quadruples his income while barely affecting the wages of native-born, and increases economic inequality as a result. The standard of living is much more important than the earnings distribution and everybody in this situation either wins or is unaffected.
5. “Today’s immigrants don’t assimilate like previous immigrant groups did.”
There is a large amount of American research that indicates immigrants are assimilating as well as or better than previous immigrant groups – even Mexicans. [Don’t tell the Trumpanzees - Ed.] The first piece of research is the National Academy of Science’s (NAS) September 2015 book titled The Integration of Immigrants into American Society. It’s a thorough and brilliant summation of the relevant academic literature on immigrant assimilation. Bottom line: Assimilation is never perfect and always takes time, but it’s going very well.
The second book is a July 2015 book entitled Indicators of Immigrant Integration 2015 that analyses immigrant and second generation integration on 27 measurable indicators across the OECD and EU countries. This report finds more problems with immigrant assimilation in Europe, especially for those from outside of the European Union, but the findings for the United States are quite positive.
The third work by University of Washington economist Jacob Vigdor compares modern immigrant civic and cultural assimilation to that of immigrants from the early 20th century (an earlier draft of his book chapter is here, the published version is available in this collection). If you think early 20th century immigrants and their descendants eventually assimilated successfully, Vigdor’s conclusion is reassuring:
While there are reasons to think of contemporary migration from Spanish-speaking nations as distinct
from earlier waves of immigration, evidence does not support the notion that this wave of migration poses
a true threat to the institutions that withstood those earlier waves. Basic indicators of assimilation,
from naturalisation to English ability, are if anything stronger now than they were a century ago.
For the nostalgic among us who believe that immigrants assimilated so much more smoothly in the “melting pot” in the past, the plethora of ethnic and anti-Catholic riots, the nativist Know-Nothing movement, and immigrant groups that refused to assimilate are a useful tonic. Immigrant assimilation is always messy and it always looks bad from the middle of that process where we are right now, but the trends are positive and pointing in the right direction.
6. “Immigrants are especially crime prone.”
This myth has been around for over a century. It wasn’t true in 1896, 1909, 1931,1994, and more recently. Immigrants are less likely to be incarcerated for violent and property crimes and cities with more immigrants, and their descendants are more peaceful. Some immigrants do commit violent and property crimes but, on the whole, they are less likely to do so.
7. “Immigrants pose a unique risk today because of terrorism.”
Terrorism is not a modern strategy. There were a large number of bombings and terrorist attacks in the early 20th century, most of them committed by immigrants, socialists, and their fellow travellers.
Today, the deaths from terrorism committed by immigrants are greater than they were a century ago but the risk is still low compared to the benefits of immigration. For instance, the chance of an American being killed in a terrorist attack committed on U.S. soil by a refugee was one in 3.6 billion from 1975 to 2015. For all foreign-born terrorists on U.S. soil, the chance of being murdered in a terrorist attack is one in 3.6 million during the same period of time. Almost 99 percent of those murders occurred on 9/11 and were committed by foreigners on tourist visas and one student visa, not immigrants. Cato has a paper coming out in September that explores this in greater detail. Every death from terrorism is a tragedy but immigrants pose a relatively small threat relative to the big benefits of them being here (remember the immigration surplus above).
8. “It’s easy to immigrate to America and we’re the most open country in the world.”
It is very difficult to immigrate to the United States. Ellis Island closed down a long time ago. In most cases, there isn’t a line and when there is, it can take decades or centuries. This chart shows the confusing and difficult path to a green card. Does that look easy to you?
America allows greater numbers of immigrants than any other country. However, the annual flow of immigrants as a percent of our population is below most other OECD countries because the United States is so large. The percentage of our population that is foreign-born is about 13 percent – below historical highs in the United States and less than half of what it is in modern New Zealand and Australia. America is great at assimilating immigrants but other countries are much more open.
9. “Amnesty or failure to enforce our immigration laws will destroy the Rule of Law.”
For a law to be consistent with Rule of Law principle, it must be applied equally, have roughly ex ante predictable outcomes based on the circumstances, and be consistent with our Anglo-Saxon traditions of personal autonomy and liberty. Our current immigration laws violate all of those. They are applied differently based on people’s country of birth via arbitrary quotas and other regulations, the outcomes are certainly not predictable, and they are hardly consistent with any conception of liberty.
For the Rule of Law to be present, good laws are required, not just strict adherence to government enforcement of impossible to follow rules.
Enforcing laws that are inherently capricious and that are contrary to liberty is inconsistent with a stable Rule of Law that is a necessary, although not sufficient, precondition for economic growth. Enforcing bad laws poorly is better than enforcing bad laws uniformly despite the uncertainty. In immigration, poor enforcement of our destructive laws is preferable to strict enforcement but liberalisation is the best choice of all.
10. “National sovereignty.”
By not exercising control over borders through actively blocking immigrants, the users of this argument warn, governments surrender a vital component of national sovereignty. Rarely do users of this argument explain to whom the government would actually surrender sovereignty in this situation. Even in the most extremely open immigration policy imaginable, total open borders, national sovereignty is not diminished assuming that a government’s institutions chose such a policy (I am not supporting totally open borders here, I am just using it as a foil to show that even in this extreme situation this argument fails). How can that be?
The standard Weberian definition of a government is an institution that has a monopoly (or near monopoly) on the legitimate use of force within a certain geographical area. The way it achieves this monopoly is by keeping out other competing sovereigns that want to be that monopoly. Our government maintains its sovereignty is by excluding the militaries of other nations [mostly by hope in New Zealand’s case – Ed.] and by stopping insurgents.
However, immigration laws are not primarily designed or intended to keep out foreign armies, spies, or insurgents. The main effect of immigration laws is to keep out willing foreign workers from selling their labour to voluntary local purchasers. Such economic controls do not aid in the maintenance of national sovereignty and relaxing or removing them would not infringe upon the government’s national sovereignty any more than a policy of unilateral free trade would. Allowing the free flow of non-violent and healthy foreign nationals does nothing to diminish the government’s legitimate monopoly on the use of force in the Weberian world.
Furthermore, national sovereign control over immigrations means that the government can do whatever it wants with that power – including relinquishing it entirely. It would be odd to argue that sovereign states have complete control over their border except they can’t open them too much. Of course, they can – that is the essence of sovereignty. After all, I’m arguing that the government should change its laws to allow for more legal immigration, not that the government should cede all of its power to a foreign sovereign.
11. “Immigrants won’t vote for the right party – look at what happened to California.”
This is an argument used by some conservatives to oppose liberalised immigration. They point to my home state of California as an example of what happens when there are too many immigrants and their descendants: Democratic control. The evidence is clear that Hispanic and immigrant voters in California in the early to mid-1990s did turn the state blue but that was a reaction to the state GOP declaring political war on them. Those who claim that changing demographics due to immigration is solely responsible for the shift in California’s politics have to explain the severe drop-off in support for the GOP at exactly the same time that the party was using anti-immigration propositions and arguments to win the 1994 election.
They would further have to why Texas Hispanics are so much more Republican than those in California. Nativism has never been the path toward national party success and frequently contributes to their downfall. In other words, whether immigrants vote for conservatives is mostly up to how conservatives treat them.
Republicans should look toward the inclusive and relatively pro-immigration policies and positions adopted by their fellow party members in Texas and their subsequent electoral success there rather than trying to replicate the foolish nativist politics pursued by the California Republican Party. My comment here assumes that locking people out of the United States because they might disproportionality vote for one of the two major parties is a legitimate use of government power – I do not believe that it is.
12. “Immigrants bring with them their bad cultures, ideas, or other factors that will undermine and destroy our economic and political institutions. The resultant weakening in economic growth means that immigrants will destroy more wealth than they will create.”
This is the most intelligent anti-immigration argument and the one most likely to be correct, although the evidence currently doesn’t support it being true. Economist Michael Clemens lays out a wonderful model of how immigrants could theoretically weaken the growth potential of any receiving countries. In his model, he assumes that immigrants transmit these anti-growth factors to the United States. However, as the immigrants assimilate into American ideas and notions, these anti-growth factors weaken over time. Congestion could counteract that assimilation process when there are too many immigrants with too many bad ideas, thus overwhelming assimilative forces. Clemens is rightly skeptical that this is occurring but his paper lays out the theoretical point where immigration restrictions would be efficient – where they balance the benefits of economic expansion from immigration with the costs of institutional degradation.
Empirical evidence doesn’t point to this effect either. In a recent academic paper, my coauthors and I compared economic freedom scores with immigrant populations across 100 countries over 21 years. Some countries were majority immigrant while some had virtually none. We found that the larger a country’s immigrant population was in 1990, the more economic freedom increased in the same country by 2011. The immigrant’s country of origin, and whether they came from a poor nation or a rich one, didn’t affect the outcome. These results held for the United States federal government but not for state governments. States with greater immigrant populations in 1990 had less economic freedom in 2011 than those with fewer immigrants, but the difference was small. The national increase in economic freedom more than outweighed the small decrease in economic freedom in states with more immigrants. Large immigrant populations also don’t increase the size of welfare programmes or other public programmes across American states, and there is a lot of evidence that more immigrants in European countries actually decreases support for big government.
Although this anti-immigration argument could be true, [more particularly as locals embrace phony ideas of multiculturalism that denigrate the very western culture immigrants have often moved to embrace – Ed.] it seems unlikely to be so for several reasons. First, it is very hard to upend established political and economic institutions through immigration. Immigrants change to fit into the existing order rather than vice versa. Institutions are ontologically collective – my American conceptions of private property rights wouldn’t accompany me in any meaningful way if I went to Cuba and vice versa. It would take a rapid inundation of immigrants and replacement of natives to change institutions in most places.
The second possibility is immigrant self-selection: Those who decide to come here mostly admire western institutions or have policy opinions that are very similar to those of the native-born. As a result, adding more immigrants who already broadly share local opinions would not affect policy. This appears to be the case in the United States.
The third explanation is that more open immigration makes native voters oppose welfare or expanded government because they believe immigrants will disproportionately consume the benefits (regardless of the fact that poor immigrants actually under—consume welfare compared to poor locals). In essence, voters hold back the expansion of those programs based on the belief that immigrants may take advantage of them. As Paul Krugman aptly observed,
Absent those [immigration] restrictions, there would have
been many claims, justified or not, about people flocking
to America to take advantage of [New Deal] welfare programmes.
As the late labour historian (and immigration restrictionist) Vernon M. Briggs Jr. wrote,
This era [of immigration restrictions] witnessed the enactment [in the US] of the most progressive worker
and family legislation the nation has ever adopted.None of those big-government programmes would have been politically possible to create amidst mass immigration. Government grows the fastest when immigration is the most restricted, and it slows dramatically when the borders are more open.
Even Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels thought that the prospects for working class revolution in the United States were diminished due to the varied immigrant origins of the workers who were divided by a high degree of ethnic, sectarian, and racial diversity. That immigrant-led diversity may be why the United States never had a popular workers, labour, or socialist party.
The most plausible argument against liberalising immigration is that immigrants will worsen economic and political institutions, thus slowing economic growth and killing the goose that lays the golden eggs. Fortunately, the academic and policy literature does not support this argument and there is some evidence that immigration could actually improve our institutions. Even the best argument against immigration is still unconvincing.
13. “The brain drain of smart immigrants to the United State impoverished other countries.”
The results of the empirical evidence on this point are conclusive: The flow of skilled workers from low-productivity countries to high-productivity nations increases the incomes of people in the destination country, enriches the immigrant, and helps (or at least doesn’t hurt) those left behind. Furthermore, remittances that immigrants send home are often large enough to offset any loss in home country productivity by emigration. In the long run, the potential to immigrate and the higher returns from education increase the incentive for workers in the Developing World to acquire skills that they otherwise might not – increasing the quantity of human capital. Instead of being called a brain drain, this phenomenon should be accurately called a skill flow.
Economic development should be about increasing the incomes of people not the amount of economic activity in specific geographical regions. Immigration and emigration do just that.
14. “Immigrants will increase crowding, harm the environment, and [insert misanthropic statement here].”
The late economist Julian Simon spent much of his career showing that people are an economic and environmental blessing, not a curse. Despite his work, numerous anti-immigration organisations today were funded and founded to oppose immigration because it would increase the number of high-income Americans who would then harm the environment more. Yes, seriously – just read about John Tanton who is the Johnny Appleseed of modern American nativism.
Concern about crowding is focused on publicly-provided goods or services – like schools, roads, and heavily zoned urban areas. Private businesses don’t complain about crowding, they expand to meet demand which increases their profits. If crowding was really an issue then privatising government functions so they have an incentive to rapidly meet demand is a cheap and easy option. Even if the government doesn’t do that, and sadly I don’t suspect they will in the near future, the problems of crowding are manageable because more immigrants also mean a larger tax base. Reforming or removing local land use laws that prevent development would also go a long way to alleviating any concerns over crowding.
Although we should think of these issues on the margin, would you rather be stuck with the problems of crowding like they have in St Tropez in summer or the problem of not enough crowding like in Detroit?
15. “Some races and ethnic groups are genetically inferior. They need to be prevented from coming here, breeding, and decreasing America’s good ethnic stock.”
These arguments were more popular a century ago when notions of eugenics and racism were widely believed, based on extraordinarily bad research, and were some of the main arguments for passage of the American Immigration Act of 1924 that took down Lady Liberty’s welcoming lamp from beside the Gold Door. They have resurfaced on Twitter and in the more fetid comments sections of some blogs, but these types of arguments still aren’t publicly aired very often and are quite silly. I don’t spend time engaging with them but I had to mention that they are still out there.
There are other arguments that people use in opposition to immigration. Many of those arguments revolve around issues of “fairness” – a word with a fuzzy meaning that differs dramatically between people and cultures. Arguments about fairness often depend on feelings and, usually, a misunderstanding of the facts that is quickly corrected by reference to my 8th point above.
Alex Nowrasteh is the immigration policy analyst at the
Cato Institute’s Center for Global Liberty and Prosperity.
A version of this post previously appeared at FEE.
.
7 comments:
Yuuup...#7 the fact that a union boofhead (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Albert_Horsley) or anarchist (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/1919_United_States_anarchist_bombings) may have had a crack at you in the early 1900s sure is a great argument as to why immigration under contemporary geopolitics is a win-win
Nope....solid as
No Islam Immigrants to New Zealand. New Zealanders first. Nationhood and strength. We will be reforming the open border Nanny state Immigration process after 2017 election.
tldr version:
Don't wory, there's "no evidence" immigrants bring failed ideas / culture with them (point 12) Though the author graciously concedes the argument is intelligent and possibly correct.
These ideas may cause the immigrant to vote for the "wrong" political party (point 11) but those parties can just change their policy to appeal to the people with failed ideas.
Terrorism (point 7) and lower wages (point 1) are real but the effects are "small".
Welfarism (point 2) is only an issue if you make the wrong policy choices. Just ignore points 11 & 12 when making policy!
How could you not be convinced?
Too bad none of this current invasion force are immigrants.
New Zealand's problem is there are not enough middle-eastern muslims immigrants. If we just imported all the poor and disposed millions from there all of New Zealand's problems would be solved.
I still for the life of me can't understand why all you simpletons don't agree.
I like the old photos you show in these arguments. Families standing in disciplined and orderly lines as they look to enter and engage in a new land to build something that will improve the lives of their descendants. I think its a stark contrast to rivers of Muslims barging in to western Europe and maintaining the crude behaviour of their homelands.
3:16
Many of Nowratesh's arguments are false, or false in the context of modern America, or incomplete. #1: Low-skilled immigrants do in fact lower wages for low-skilled American workers, or more usually, throw low-skilled American workers onto public assistance. This is different from the 19th century when the US was capital poor and low skilled laborers could find plenty of things to do without learning. Now, with the US being a capital rich country, to take part in those riches, labor needs the skills to make use of the capital. A low skilled worker can dig a ditch with a shovel, but he can't compete with a back-hoe. He has to learn to operate the back hoe to compete. In examples where the capital is more complex even than a back-hoe, this learning may not even be possible for some.
#2 and #3: Immigrants from *some* countries are welfare prone, while immigrants from other countries are not. Refugees and asylees are not only eligible for all welfare programs citizens are, there are even special extra programs for them not available to citizens! You can understand this better by noting that open borders zealots like the author always refer to welfare usage per person, while the appropriate measure is per household. Two immigrants (legal or not) with a child born in the US (an "anchor baby") are themselves not eligible for many welfare benefits, but the CHILD IS ELIGIBLE, and thee payments don't go to the child but the parents. So by looking at welfare usage BY HOUSEHOLD, rather than by individual, a more accurate picture is painted of immigrant welfare usage.
#6: Immigrants from SOME countries are much more violent and criminal as from other countries. Though good data is sparse, and so no overall conclusion is possible within the margin of error as to whether immigrants AS A WHOLE are more violent than Americans (remember, "Americans" include black men ages 16-35 who commit almost half the violent crimes in the US, which skews the statistics wildly upward) or or less violent, it is beyond doubt that immigrants from SOME countries are more violent than Americans as a whole, while immigrants from OTHER countries are not. Immigration zealots never tell us why we can't choose to have more of the latter and fewer of the former.
#12: " Immigrants change to fit into the existing order rather than vice versa." this is not true today in the US, and has never been true in the US, and it has never been true around the world throughout world history. Advocate open borders for Israel, for example, and see how well the immigrants will "fit into the existing order". It's ridiculous. The quote from known liar Paul Krugman seals the deal on this issue.
Post a Comment